Friday, May 25, 2012
America's potential GDP
Remembering
when the future kept getting bigger
May 24th 2012, 17:17 by G.I. |
WASHINGTON
HOW big can the American economy
grow? This week’s Free exchange column tackles the critical question of America’s potential: the
maximum output it can sustain given its endowments of capital, labour and
technology.
The article notes that economic
growth since the recession ended three years ago has averaged 2.5% a year. That
is roughly the trend rate of an economy already at full employment. Given that
America is still in a deep post-recession hole, such a rate should not be
enough to reduce unemployment, and should have left so much spare capacity that
inflation ought to have fallen sharply. Instead, unemployment has dropped
nearly two percentage points in that time and underlying inflation, after
dipping below 1%, is above 2%.
While various idiosyncratic factors
can explain this behaviour, it could also be a sign that the crisis has
significantly eroded potential GDP, and the output gap is much smaller than
generally realised. (This is a topic on which I’ve blogged before, here, here and here.) Since 2005 the Congressional Budget Office has revised down
its estimate of potential GDP in the year 2012 by 5%.
Doing this exercise for the late
1990s, a completely different picture emerges. As the accompanying chart shows,
in 1997, the CBO estimated potential in early 2001 would be $8.3 trillion (in
constant 1996 dollars). By 2001, it had revised that up a whopping 12%, to $9.3
trillion, a figure that looks more reasonable given what we now know GDP
actually did.
The CBO’s shifting estimates of
potential illustrate two things. One is that potential is almost impossible to
pin down in real time since the economy’s equilibrium long-run stock of capital
and labour are so difficult to estimate with precision; so we look at what GDP
actually did as a hint of what it can do.
Second, and more important, is that supply
(i.e. potential) is itself affected by demand. Potential output is the product
of capital, labour and innovation. Since economic booms bring more investment,
more risk-taking, and higher labour force participation, they push up measures
of potential. The opposite is true of busts. If overall spending is depressed
long enough, many workers will experience prolonged unemployment that degrades
their skills, making them unemployable; they may eventually quit the labour
force altogether.
Depressed sales also discourage investment in new technology
and research, which can degrade productivity and efficiency for years to come.
(A counter argument is that depressions may hasten the migration of capital and
labour from dying, low-productivity sectors to growing, high-productivity ones.
Apparently, scholars are still arguing over whether this happened in the
1930s.) Powerful evidence for this phenomenon comes in a paper that my
colleague A.C.S. discussed Monday which found most structural unemployment begins
during recessions.
It follows that efforts to preserve
demand can also preserve the economy’s supply-side potential. That, too, seems
to be one of the lessons of international experience. It is not too late for
America to limit most of the long-run damage of its crisis; but it may soon be.
(Note:
special thanks to Brent Moulton of the Commerce Department’s Bureau of Economic
Analysis for technical advice on how to convert real GDP figures to a common
base year.)
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.