1. |
| 490.59 | ||
2. |
| 389.53 | ||
3. |
| 302.51 | ||
4. |
| 241.39 | ||
5. |
| 188.24 | ||
6. |
| 176.06 | ||
7. |
| 162.36 | ||
8. |
| 147.72 | ||
9. |
| 145.61 | ||
10. |
| 103.15 | ||
11. |
| 83.05 | ||
12. |
| 77.87 | ||
13. |
| 69.84 | ||
14. |
| 67.96 | ||
15. |
| 43.75 | ||
16. |
| 32.88 | ||
17. |
| 25.46 | ||
18. |
| 22.91 | ||
19. |
| 22.19 | ||
20. |
| 17.20 |
Wednesday, March 27, 2013
List of Most Generous Countries
Top Ten Poorest Countries
The Top Ten Poorest Countries map has been prepared on the basis of the GDP of a country. A country with a GDP per capita of $765 dollars or less is defined as a low-income or poor country. |
|
The Philippines and Malaysia:Intrusion confusion
This summary is not available. Please
click here to view the post.
Malaysia’s looming election:Video nasties
A two-year election campaign nears its climax
WITH a tight election coming up, it is politics as usual in
Malaysia—only more so. This month alone has seen the opposition accused
of colluding in a foreign invasion of the state of Sabah in Borneo; the
death of a private investigator, reviving stories of the grisly murder
in 2006 of a beautiful Mongolian woman linked to a friend of the prime
minister, Najib Razak; the leader of the opposition, Anwar Ibrahim,
denying that he was one of two men appearing in grainy pictures online
in an affectionate clinch; and a film shot on hidden cameras that
appears to show large-scale corruption in the government of the other
Malaysian state in Borneo, Sarawak.
Sailing blithely above the mud and filth that make Malaysian
political waters so murky, Mr Najib went on national television on March
19th to deliver the scorecard on the “transformation programme” his
government has implemented. He had a good story to tell, of robust
economic growth of 5.6% in 2012, poverty virtually eliminated,
inequality reduced and 400 legal cases against corruption initiated. And
he was able to announce that a scheme to give cash handouts to poorer
households will become an annual event.
All should be set fair, you might think, for Mr Najib’s ruling
coalition, the Barisan Nasional (BN), to romp home again at the
election, as it has done in every ballot since independence in 1957. Mr
Najib is expected to dissolve parliament any day now, with the voting to
follow in mid-April after a brief official campaign period (the
unofficial one has now lasted two years or more). If he does not
dissolve parliament, its term will expire at the end of April, and the
election must then be held by the end of June.
In fact, the outcome is in doubt, for the first time in Malaysia’s
history. In the election five years ago the opposition coalition, the
Pakatan Rakyat, for the first time deprived the BN of the two-thirds
majority that allows it to change the constitution. That led to the
downfall of the BN prime minister of the day, Abdullah Badawi. His
replacement by Mr Najib was decided by their party, the United Malays
National Organisation (UMNO), which represents the Malays (who make up
about 55% of the population) and dominates the BN. In 2008 Pakatan
actually won a slight majority of the popular vote in peninsular
Malaysia (ie, excluding Sabah and Sarawak). Affirmative-action policies
introduced more than 40 years ago to favour Malays and other indigenous
groups over the Chinese and Indian minorities were no longer enough to
ensure an overwhelming victory for the ruling coalition.
The BN says it would like to campaign on Mr Najib’s record of
relative economic success, modest liberalising reform and statesmanship.
The opposition wants to keep the focus on issues of fairness and
corruption. It can boast of good performances by governments in some of
the four (out of 13) states it controls in Malaysia’s federal system.
But its best hope is that, after more than five decades of BN rule, many
Malaysians want change.
This time, some Pakatan members express utter confidence that it will
come. That is probably bluster. The odds still favour the BN.
Constituency sizes give greater weight to voters in the countryside, who
tend to be more conservative than the wired, cosmopolitan and cynical
residents of the cities. Mr Najib has the advantages of incumbency—such
as deciding when to call elections. Waiting has deprived the opposition
of the chance of postponing elections in the four states it governs.
Simultaneous elections tend to favour the BN, with its greater
resources.
The risk in waiting has been that unexpected events might intervene.
One such has been the extraordinary saga of the “invasion” of Sabah in
February by nearly 200 gunmen calling themselves followers of a
pretender to the title of the Sultan of Sulu, whose holder in the
southern Philippines once ruled Sabah as well. What seemed at first a
kind of practical joke turned into an extremely ugly confrontation, in
which 62 of the intruders and ten men from the Malaysian security forces
have died.
The suspicions of opposition involvement (vigorously denied) stem
from the composition of Sabah’s population. A commission is
investigating the award of Malaysian citizenship in the 1990s to about
800,000 Filipino Muslims. The BN is accused of trying to change the
ethnic make-up of Sabah, and of importing potential voters. Sabahans of
Filipino origin, however, might be alienated by a fierce crackdown on
the intruders. Perhaps with that in mind, coverage of the mopping-up
operation on state-controlled television stations has been low-key.
Indeed, even if the invasion might harm the BN in Sabah, the
government’s handling of it may have helped it overall.
Nor will the government be much worried by the impact of the death
from a heart attack on March 15th of a private investigator who in 2008
had accused the prime minister of having been involved with a Mongolian
woman. His death has revived interest in the story of her murder in 2006
by two members of an elite commando corps. Mr Najib has sworn on the
Koran that he never met the woman, and although the case continues to
create excited chatter online, it is ignored by the mainstream press. In
opinion polls, Mr Najib remains very popular, with an approval rating
of 61% in one recent survey.
The steady stream of improbable allegations of sexual impropriety
against Mr Anwar, however, although always denied, may have eroded his
standing. They may also create tensions within Pakatan, whose three
components are Mr Anwar’s multi-ethnic party, a conservative Islamist
one and the Democratic Action Party, dominated by members of the
ethnic-Chinese minority. Perversely, some Chinese remain worried by Mr
Anwar for a different reason: his early days as a firebrand Islamist
student leader.
That he still has some chance of becoming prime minister is testimony
to widespread anger at the corruption endemic in Malaysia. The
hidden-camera film on Sarawak, produced by Global Witness, a
London-based NGO, produced shocking evidence of state-government
criminality in land deals. Its many viewers in Malaysia are furious. But
they are not surprised
Saturday, March 9, 2013
Greece may still have to quit euro
March 10, 2013
Alexander Dobrindt, general secretary of the Christian Social Union
(CSU), the Bavaria-based sister party of Merkel’s Christian Democrats
(CDU), has long argued that Greece would be better off outside the euro
zone.
But German conservatives’ criticism of Greece has eased since the
conservative-led government of Prime Minister Antonis Samaras
accelerated harsh austerity measures demanded by Germany and the EU as
part of its bailout programme.
“The greatest risk for the euro is still Greece... I still believe
that Greece’s exit would be a possible long-term alternative, for Europe
and for Greece itself,” Dobrindt told Die Welt am Sonntag newspaper,
according to advance excerpts of the interview released yesterday.
“We have created a situation that gives Greece a chance to return to
stability and restore competitiveness. But I still hold that, if Greece
is not able or willing to restore stability, then there must be a way
outside the euro zone.”
Dobrindt urged the European Commission, the EU’s executive arm, to
prepare the legal ground to allow for the legal bankruptcy of a euro
zone member state and its exit from the currency union.
Dobrindt’s comments contrasted with those of the CSU chairman and
Bavarian state premier, Horst Seehofer, who expressed solidarity with
Greece and said it was on the “right path” when Samaras visited Munich
last December.
Seehofer’s conciliatory tone echoed that of Merkel who, for all her
frustration with the slow pace of Greek reforms, has decided that a
“Grexit” would be far more costly for Germany and Europe than pressing
on with the bailout programme.
Merkel is also keen to avoid renewed market turbulence in the euro
zone ahead of Germany’s federal election in September. Bavaria also
holds a state election in the autumn which the CSU is tipped to win.
Dobrindt made headlines last summer when he suggested Greece should
start paying half of its pensions and state salaries in drachmas - the
national Greek currency before the euro - as part of a gradual exit from
the euro zone.
With Athens now enjoying relative political stability, German
lawmakers have recently been more focused on how to rescue Cyprus, which
is negotiating a bailout after its banks suffered big losses due to
their heavy exposure to Greece.
Italy, the euro zone’s third largest economy, also poses a bigger
challenge after a majority of voters there rejected German-backed
austerity policies in an election last month that has left no party with
a clear majority to govern. – Reuters
Thursday, March 7, 2013
The Eurozone Debt Crisis: 2013 Could Be A Watershed Year
After more than three years of economic, financial, and budgetary
stress in the European Economic and Monetary Union (eurozone),
especially on its so-called "periphery", some signs of stabilization
emerged in the latter half of 2012. Is this a sign that the financial
and economic troubles leading to the rating downgrades of 12 of the 17
eurozone member states since the onset of the crisis may have run their
course? We believe that 2013 could be a watershed year for the eurozone
debt crisis. It could mark the start of the region sustainably
overcoming the market volatility and fragmentation that has affected it
over the past few years. It could also see the return of some so-called
"program countries"--member states that have borrowed from the European
Stability Mechanism (ESM) or the European Financial Stability Facility
multilateral loan programs--such as Ireland and Portugal, to more
substantial primary issuance in the capital markets.
Still, we see several qualifications to this positive scenario.
We believe that investor confidence will only return if member states
continue to make progress in rebalancing their economies, both through
structurally stabilizing public debt and by further reducing external
deficits. Achieving this will take a disciplined and transparent
response from policymakers both at national and European levels.
Safeguards to the social contract may also be necessary to assist in the
cohesion of those member states suffering from high unemployment,
excessive private leverage, and stagnating or falling living standards.
In our view, this is a challenging but achievable agenda, although
implementation risks loom large. These risks are the main reason that
the majority of our outlooks on our eurozone sovereign ratings are still
negative (see table 3, including one sovereign, Slovenia, on
CreditWatch Negative). Nevertheless, European leaders have laid, or at
least announced, much of the groundwork for the eurozone to emerge from
its lingering crisis.
- We expect 2013 to be a watershed year in determining whether the eurozone can emerge from its sovereign debt troubles.
- European policymakers have, in our view, laid some of the groundwork for a recovery.
- The eurozone's success in reversing its credit trends will depend on national and pan-European policymakers' responses to the eurozone's continuing economic, political, and social risks.
2012: A Year Of Two Halves
The past year was another eventful one for eurozone sovereign
creditworthiness and ratings. 2012 included the first default of a rated
sovereign that is now part of the eurozone, Greece (B-/Stable/B). The
year began with the downgrade of nine eurozone sovereign ratings in
mid-January, including the loss of the 'AAA' ratings that Austria and
France had held for more than three decades. The rating actions were
primarily driven by our assessment that the policy initiatives taken by
European policymakers insufficiently addressed numerous eurozone
systemic stresses. In early 2012, European policy seemed based on a
consensus that the eurozone's financial problems stemmed primarily from
fiscal profligacy at its periphery. In our view, however, these problems
were rooted at least as much in the increased external imbalances and
competitive divergences between the eurozone's core and its periphery.
We think the periphery has only sustained its competitive
underperformance (manifested by the periphery's sizable external
deficits) by funding from the banking systems of the more competitive
core eurozone member states. We believe that our remarks made in January
2012 still apply: that "a reform process based on a pillar of fiscal
austerity alone risks becoming self-defeating as domestic demand falls
in line with consumers' rising concerns about job security and
disposable incomes, eroding national tax revenues" (see: "Credit FAQ: Factors Behind Our Rating Actions On Eurozone Sovereign Governments," Jan. 13, 2012).
In our view, it was thus unsurprising that sovereign bonds of
peripheral sovereigns continued to come under pressure, especially once
the effect of the €1 trillion long-term refinancing operations (LTRO)
conducted by the European Central Bank (ECB, unsolicited ratings
AAA/Stable/A-1+) had worn off. For example, the yield of the 10-year
bond of the Kingdom of Spain (BBB-/Negative/A-3) hovered just over 5%
during the first quarter of 2012, supported by what we believe to have
been intense buying by Spanish banks, which themselves borrowed heavily
from the LTRO. With that support gone and the crisis showing no signs of
abating, Spanish sovereign yields peaked above 7% over the summer.
As matters worsened, threatening to engulf larger nations like
Italy (and, as suggested above, Spain), the European policy reaction
took on a broader perspective. Policymakers began to recognize that a
strategy based on fiscal austerity alone could have other negative
economic and social consequences. We believe that policymakers began to
realize that they were confronting not only a budgetary problem of
excessive public debt and deficits, but a series of balance-of-payments
problems as well--a view, incidentally, in line with our own long-held
opinions (see "Who Will Solve the Debt Crisis," published Nov. 10, 2011).
From today's vantage point, it appears there were two events in
2012 that helped begin to restore credibility in European policymakers'
approach:
- The June 29 eurozone summit that granted flexibility to the ESM, the eurozone's permanent bailout fund that became operational in the second half of 2012, to directly purchase bonds in the primary market. Once a single bank supervisory mechanism is established at the level of the eurozone, the ESM would also be allowed to directly recapitalize banks, thus breaking the vicious circle between vulnerable governments and weakly capitalized banks. The summit also decided to expedite progress toward a banking union, starting with the establishment of a single supervisory banking authority (see "The Tide May Be Turning For Eurozone Sovereigns Following The June 29 Summit," published July 3, 2012).
- The Sept. 6 ECB announcement that it would introduce "outright monetary transactions" (OMT). This allowed for unlimited bond purchases of sovereign distressed bonds by the Eurosystem (ECB and member state central banks) subject to the distressed sovereigns agreeing and adhering to explicit policy conditions see "The European Central Bank's Policy Initiatives Could Benefit Some Sovereigns, But Implementation Risks Remain," Sept. 7, 2012). At the same time, the ECB stressed that it would not seek to be treated as a preferred creditor in a future case of sovereign restructuring. The possibility that the ECB could be a preferred creditor had, in our view, previously undermined investor confidence when the Eurosystem had exempted itself from the distressed sovereign debt exchange that was a central component of Greece's workout in early 2012 (see "ECB Greek Bond Swap Results In Effective Subordination Of Private Investors," published Feb. 24, 2012).
In our opinion, both events contributed to a broad-based
recovery of bond yields. The recovery was further supported in September
2012 by the German Constitutional Court's affirmation of the
constitutionality of the ESM. Portuguese 10-year sovereign yields dipped
below 7% in December 2012 for the first time in almost two years, after
peaking at twice that level in early 2012. Greece's 2% bonds maturing
in 2023 (issued as part of its distressed debt exchange), fell to 13% of
face value in May, but recovered to (a still heavily discounted) 48% by
year end. The Spanish 10-year benchmark ended 2012 near where it
started, at just over 5%. Nevertheless, the pricing of credit default
swaps (CDS) suggests that the market still considers Spain's default
risk as elevated. By Standard & Poor's "Market Derived Signal", the
CDS market prices Spain like a 'BB' credit, two notches below our own
sovereign credit rating on Spain at 'BBB-', although this is the
smallest difference in over three years. CDS market pricing for other
periphery sovereigns also suggests that in spite of the market recovery
of late 2012, parts of the capital markets remain more pessimistic about
default probabilities on the periphery than Standard & Poor's.
Capital market pessimism about eurozone sovereign credit fundamentals
has been apparent for several years now and continues into 2013--in
contrast to its preceding optimism prior to 2008, which led to a
multiyear bond price overshooting and fundamental risk
underappreciation.
In the same vein, cross-border payment
imbalances within the eurozone, as expressed by Target 2 balances of the
Eurosystem's national central banks, peaked in the third quarter. While
the moderate decline of the imbalances in the fourth quarter signals
that cross-border funding stresses may be subsiding, we consider any
improvement to be tentative and at risk of reversal should risk aversion
of financial agents forcefully return. In fact, outstanding levels of
the Target 2 imbalances remain extremely large by historical standards.
For example, at end of December, the Target 2 balance of the Bundesbank
stood at positive €656 billion (from a peak of €750 billion in August),
while the Banco de EspaƱa's was a negative €366 billion in November
(from a peak of close to €440 billion in August). What's more, these
imbalances, which have provided an important buffer against reversing
private sector capital flows, have only reverted to the levels reached
in early 2012. The fragmentation of the eurozone financial market thus
remains extraordinarily high.
Risks In Store In 2013
Capital markets have reacted positively to the progress made by
eurozone policymakers since mid-2012 in designing a more effective
policy response to the eurozone's sovereign debt troubles. Nevertheless,
13 out of 17 eurozone sovereign ratings still carry a negative outlook
(or CreditWatch negative) largely due to our view of the risks
associated with the implementation of those policy responses. These
risks may be exacerbated if our current estimate of economic prospects
were to prove too optimistic. We expect the eurozone to shrink in 2013
by a further 0.1% (after a 0.6% contraction in 2012), as restrictive
fiscal policies, high unemployment, and falling real wages, as well as
tight credit conditions act as important drags on domestic demand in
peripheral Europe. This should allow for only a mild recovery of
positive 1% in 2014 (see "The Eurozone Enters an Uncertain 2013 As The New Recession Drags On," published Dec. 13, 2012). We expect the economies of Italy and Spain to contract by 0.7% and 1.3%, respectively.
There are in our view three main areas of risk: the economic response, the policy response, and the social response.
1. Response to economic risk
We reiterate our view that the source of the periphery's problems
(with the exception of Greece, where the root cause was largely fiscal
profligacy) lies in excessive private sector borrowing and loss of
competitiveness, leading to high current account deficits. As
cross-border funding flows suddenly stopped and then reversed, a rapid
economic rebalancing was required. The ensuing recession, in several
cases complemented by the need for the government to recapitalize
domestic financial institutions, led to large increases in public debt
and deficits. How these twin deficits are corrected will be an important
factor in our assessment of eurozone sovereign ratings during 2013 and
beyond.
But it is not only the extent of the correction (for
example, percentages of GDP) that matters, but also its social,
political, and economic sustainability. For example, eliminating a
current account deficit through import compression as a consequence of a
deep and prolonged domestic recession is, in our view, more problematic
than achieving the same improvement by boosting competitiveness and
exports. Similarly, "one-off" financial transactions or wholesale cuts
to growth-enhancing public capital expenditure are in our view less
likely to lead to sustainable consolidation and debt reduction than a
balanced approach that includes broadening tax bases and containing
consumptive spending.
Despite important progress already
achieved, in our opinion, there is no viable alternative to additional
rebalancing of the eurozone's troubled economies. The credit-fueled
growth model has ended and the volume of outstanding credit to the
private sector is now falling in many affected member states. Achieving
rebalancing is a complex and slow process, often taking ample doses of
political courage. Governments in many countries, including Greece, have
implemented adjustments, especially in the budgetary field, that are
among the most ambitious undertaken by OECD countries in half a century.
We currently expect net general government debt ratios as a share of
GDP to peak in Ireland and Italy in 2013 and those of Portugal and
Greece to grow only marginally in 2014. Nevertheless, with all those
ratios well above 100% (and close to 200% in the case of Greece) we
believe that economic rebalancing has still some way to go and will
seriously challenge political leaders.
We are also of the view
that the economic and social costs of economic rebalancing could be more
easily contained if a higher degree of policy coordination were to lead
to a more symmetrical adjustment shared between the eurozone's core
external surplus and peripheral deficit countries, rather than with most
of the burden falling on the latter.
Our assumptions regarding
the development of current account and general government fiscal
balances are summarized in tables 1 and 2. For more indicators and other
sovereigns, see "Sovereign Risk Indicators,"
published Dec. 19, 2012). If during 2013 we were to conclude that
individual sovereigns underperformed relative to those assumptions, the
relevant ratings could come under pressure in accordance with our
sovereign rating methodology (see "Sovereign Government Rating Methodology And Assumptions,"
June 30, 2011). On the other hand, sovereigns whose economic
performance generally meets or surpasses those assumptions could see a
stabilization of their respective ratings in 2013, other things being
equal.
Table 1
General Government Balance / GDP | ||||||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(%) | 2008 | 2009 | 2010 | 2011 | 2012e | 2013f | 2014f | |||||||||
Germany | (0.07) | (3.07) | (4.2) | (0.8) | (0.3) | (0.1) | (0.4) | |||||||||
Netherlands | 0.5 | (5.6) | (5.0) | (4.4) | (3.7) | (3.0) | (2.7) | |||||||||
France | (3.3) | (7.6) | (7.1) | (5.2) | (4.5) | (3.5) | (3.0) | |||||||||
Ireland | (7.4) | (13.9) | (30.9) | (13.3) | (8.4) | (7.6) | (5.2) | |||||||||
Italy | (3.0) | (5.8) | (4.8) | (3.9) | (2.7) | (2.2) | (1.7) | |||||||||
Spain | (4.5) | (11.2) | (9.7) | (9.8) | (7.9) | (5.9) | (4.5) | |||||||||
Portugal | (3.7) | (10.2) | (11.3) | (7.9) | (5.5) | (4.5) | (3.0) | |||||||||
Cyprus | 0.9 | (6.1) | (5.3) | (6.2) | (5.4) | (30.0) | (15.8) | |||||||||
Greece | (9.9) | (15.4) | (10.8) | (9.5) | (6.7) | (4.8) | (3.6) | |||||||||
e--Estimated. f--Forecast. |
Table 2
Current Account Balance / GDP | ||||||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(%) | 2008 | 2009 | 2010 | 2011 | 2012e | 2013f | 2014f | |||||||||
Germany | 6.8 | 6.6 | 6.5 | 6.4 | 6.1 | 5.2 | 4.7 | |||||||||
Netherlands | 4.3 | 5.2 | 7.7 | 9.7 | 9.2 | 9.0 | 8.9 | |||||||||
France | (1.8) | (1.4) | (1.6) | (2.0) | (2.1) | (1.8) | (2.0) | |||||||||
Ireland | (5.7) | (2.9) | 1.4 | 1.1 | 3.4 | 4.3 | 4.3 | |||||||||
Italy | (2.9) | (2.0) | (3.5) | (3.1) | (0.9) | 0.2 | 0.6 | |||||||||
Spain | (9.6) | (4.8) | (4.5) | (3.5) | (1.7) | 0.9 | 1.8 | |||||||||
Portugal | (12.6) | (10.9) | (10.0) | (6.5) | (1.9) | 0 | 0.5 | |||||||||
Cyprus | (15.6) | (10.7) | (9.8) | (4.7) | (5.9) | (4.0) | (3.5) | |||||||||
Greece | (14.9) | (11.2) | (10.1) | (9.9) | (3.2) | (2.2) | 1.1 | |||||||||
e--Estimated. F--Forecast. |
2. Response to policy risk
While there have been noteworthy new policy developments, such as OMT
and the ESM, none of these tools have yet been used and implementation
risks remain. Another key risk, in our view, would be the sense of
complacency that could develop along with an improvement in market
conditions. Complacency could lead to the fragile agreements among
European policymakers unraveling if some consider that the eurozone's
troubles have passed and previously agreed actions can be shelved or
watered down. If nothing else, such behavior would suggest a degree of
unreliability and unpredictability of eurozone economic policymaking
which could have negative consequences for the relevant ratings. Such a
policy retreat could, especially if accompanied by disappointing
adjustment progress in the periphery or rising social tensions, lead to
sell-offs in government bond markets, intensify funding squeezes, and
force policymakers to contemplate an even more costly rescue than what
would have been required had they stayed the course.
We consider
that it is too early to firmly state that complacency risk has
materialized. We are of the view, however, that the consensus among
European policymakers may be more brittle than generally appreciated.
For example, by stating in late September 2012 that banks' legacy
problem assets should remain under the responsibility of national
governments regardless of progress with a single eurozone financial
supervisor, the trilateral declaration of the finance ministers of
Germany, The Netherlands, and Finland seemed to distance those countries
from the essence of the June 2012 summit agreement. The slower process
in moving toward a banking union than had been indicated at the outset
could also be interpreted as a sign of a waning sense of urgency.
As
far as OMT is concerned, we believe that it has partially addressed the
moral hazard problem that can be a side effect of external financial
support by linking ECB intervention to borrowing member countries
meeting key policy benchmarks. The effectiveness of the OMT, which
effectively leverages the ESM, will, critically, depend on the
willingness of the governments of such borrowing member countries to
carry through with what will likely be politically and socially
contentious measures. We believe that the risks for the credibility of
the ECB could be significant should a situation arise in which
conditionality was breached due to lack of domestic political resolve.
While the ECB stated that in such cases its intent would be to cease
secondary market purchases, such an exit from intervention could, in our
view, expedite the materialization of tail-end risks that OMT had been
designed to mitigate in the first place. This emphasizes our opinion
that the key to a lasting solution of the eurozone's troubles lies with
national politicians, not with the ECB. Without resolute and sustained
reform progress, the ECB by itself can achieve only temporary respites.
We
also believe that a symmetric application of OMT could contribute to a
more robust solution of the crisis. OMT was designed to reduce the
possibility that a eurozone sovereign with satisfactory economic
fundamentals could lose market access, with Spain as the most frequently
mentioned example. But we think the OMT could also be relevant in cases
in which sovereigns (such as Ireland) currently compliant with the
conditions of a Troika program had lost, but are currently attempting to
regain, primary market access. Facilitating the successful return of
"first-generation" program countries to sustainable market funding
could, in our view, enhance confidence in the overall crisis management
strategy and, other things being equal, positively affect reform
incentives and market conditions for other sovereigns under pressure.
With
the key of successful crisis resolution in the hands of governments,
the electoral calendar remains a vital factor in assessing the future
course of policies as well as progress in crisis resolution. The main
elections in 2012, in Greece, France, and The Netherlands, resulted in
governments that took an overall constructive view on crisis resolution
efforts. These elections, in our view, reduced the possibility of
contentious discussions among policymakers that could have undermined
the delicate confidence of market participants in political leaders'
consensus and commitment to the crisis resolution strategy. It is our
base case that the elections we consider the most important in
2013--Italy in February, Germany and Austria in the autumn--will
similarly lead to a continuation of the current policy path.
In
our view, a victory of populist and anti-European forces in Italy would
have a detrimental effect on the corrections taking place in the
eurozone, especially if eurozone membership itself were to be put in
question. We note, however, that the polls do not currently signal such
an outcome as likely and we continue to consider that a member's exit
from the eurozone remains unlikely. Our assumption therefore remains
that broad policy continuity will prevail in Italy. The outcome of the
German election is at this point uncertain, but we believe that all
plausible coalition governments would support the current policy
approach, as evidenced by broad cross-party support of the relevant
parliamentary votes in the past. However, should the crisis intensify in
the run-up to the German election, we believe that the incumbent
coalition could be reluctant to promote additional measures. It would
not want to render itself subject to accusations that it is
appropriating German taxpayer funds to an ever deepening crisis with
diminishing prospects of recovering those resources. Whether additional
measures or bailout operations could be passed in the Bundestag during
the pre-electoral campaign appears to us highly uncertain.
3. Response to social risk
Many countries are experiencing the most severe economic crises in
living memory. Growth remains elusive, while official unemployment
figures have crept up to levels that, if sustained, could signal the
possibility of acute social conflict. We expect unemployment to rise in
all major economies but Germany's, and in the eurozone overall to peak
this year at a very high 12.1%, from 11.6% in 2012. However, this
average masks considerable national and sectoral differences, with, for
example, youth unemployment surpassing 50% in Greece and Spain. Many
family incomes have been affected by falling real wages and property
values as well as by unavailability of credit, leading us to believe
that the social contract around which a country coalesces may become
increasingly strained. In the longer term, we expect the already adverse
demographic profile in many countries to deteriorate further as
families have fewer or no children in light of uncertain personal
economic situations. European history well illustrates how discontent
and economic hardship can lead to support for populist or nationalist
recipes that promise easy solutions. In a worst case, such solutions
could include repudiation of public debt, nationalization, or an
outright unilateral exit from the eurozone. A prevailing sense that a
country's internal security is deteriorating alongside the population's
economic prospects could accelerate the advent of populist movements.
As
public resources become scarcer, we believe that regional or
nationalist voices may also become more alluring for the electorate. The
most visible example of this tendency was the surge in support for
independence-minded parties in the late 2012 regional election in the
Autonomous Community of Catalonia (BB/Negative/B). Although we consider a
break-up of current sovereigns as unlikely for various political,
economic, and constitutional reasons, we nevertheless acknowledge that
escalation of fundamental constitutional conflicts will complicate the
implementation of unpopular economic policy measures considered
necessary to curtail the twin external and fiscal deficits.
While populist parties have sprung up in several countries, the
partisan landscape in Greece has radicalized most, concomitant with the
deepest economic depression in the region. While voters have hitherto
endorsed more centrist coalitions, the risk of radicalization rises the
longer a tangible recovery fails to occur. Further radicalization, while
not in our 2013 base case, could make its effects felt across the
eurozone, leading to a return of doubts about the irreversibility of
eurozone membership, which had been pushed to the background since the
unveiling of the OMT initiative.
Sovereign Creditworthiness Is In The Hands Of Policymakers
All things considered, we believe the challenges in the eurozone
remain formidable. Our current 'CCC+' rating on Cyprus signals our
opinion that we could see another eurozone sovereign being forced to
restructure its obligations and effectively default under our criteria
(see "Rating Implications Of Exchange Offers And Similar Restructurings, Update,"
published May 12, 2009). With Cyprus accounting for only 0.2% of
eurozone GDP and being considered as a special case most directly
affected by the Greek crisis, we think it unlikely that the eurozone's
path to recovery will be determined by a restructuring in Cyprus, should
one occur in 2013.
All the same, we expect 2013 to be a critical year in determining
whether the multiyear downward trajectory of sovereign ratings in the
eurozone, which had already begun in 2004 with the downgrades of Greece
and Italy, will, at last, come to an end. We believe that as the year
progresses, visibility of the economic, policy, and social responses to
the crisis will become clearer. Should the abovementioned risks not
materialize and social cohesion coexist along with disciplined policy
implementation and progress in economic and fiscal rebalancing, the
prospects would indeed be realistic for us to conclude that eurozone
sovereign creditworthiness had "bottomed out".
Nevertheless,
Standard & Poor's eurozone sovereign ratings have been lowered in a
more measured fashion than the more volatile reactions of the sovereign
bond and CDS markets. As we enter 2013, only three out of 17 sovereigns
have a noninvestment-grade rating (Portugal, Cyprus, and Greece),
accounting for less than 4% of estimated 2012 eurozone GDP. The
GDP-weighted average sovereign rating is still at a very strong 'AA-',
down from 'AA+' at the onset of the crisis, indicating our view of the
high degree of resilience of the generally prosperous and diversified
economies and high levels of governance of member states. We believe
that it is in the hands of policymakers and societies to prevent a
further slide of sovereign creditworthiness and that 2013 will be a
decisive year in that respect.
Table 3
Eurozone Sovereign Long-Term Ratings And Outlooks | --As of Dec. 31, 2006-- | --As of Dec. 31, 2009 | --As of Dec. 31, 2012 | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Long-term rating | Outlook | Long-term rating | Outlook | Long-term rating | Outlook | |
Finland (Republic of) | AAA | Stable | AAA | Stable | AAA | Negative |
Germany (Federal Republic of) | AAA | Stable | AAA | Stable | AAA | Stable |
Luxembourg (Grand Duchy of) | AAA | Stable | AAA | Stable | AAA | Negative |
Netherlands (The) (State of) | AAA | Stable | AAA | Stable | AAA | Negative |
Austria (Republic of) | AAA | Stable | AAA | Stable | AA+ | Negative |
France (Republic of) | AAA | Stable | AAA | Stable | AA+ | Negative |
Belgium (Kingdom of) | AA+ | Stable | AA+ | Stable | AA | Negative |
Estonia (Republic of) | A | Stable | A- | Negative | AA- | Stable |
Slovak Republic | A | Stable | A+ | Stable | A | Stable |
Slovenia (Republic of) | AA | Stable | AA | Stable | A | Watch Neg |
Malta (Republic of) | A | Stable | A | Stable | A- | Negative |
Ireland (Republic of) | AAA | Stable | AA | Negative | BBB+ | Negative |
Italy (Republic of) | A+ | Stable | A+ | Stable | BBB+ | Negative |
Spain (Kingdom of) | AAA | Stable | AA+ | Negative | BBB- | Negative |
Portugal (Republic of) | AA- | Stable | A+ | Negative | BB | Negative |
Cyprus (Republic of) | A | Stable | A+ | Stable | CCC+ | Negative |
Greece (Hellenic Republic) | A | Stable | BBB+ | Watch Neg | B- |
Stable |
|
Malaysia’s Economy: Still Chugging Along
By James Parker
Malaysia’s economic performance does not make headlines like
it used to, but that does not mean that the economy is not still
chugging along nicely.
In fact, with the exception of difficult periods following major
shocks such as the 2008 Global Financial Crisis, Malaysian GDP growth
has performed well over the last decade, averaging about 5% since late
2010. The latest data for the third quarter showed GDP growth of 5.2%.
These rates, while not as spectacular as China’s, are nonetheless
extremely encouraging when compared to the developed nations of Europe
and North America. Furthermore, domestic demand (a key strength in a
world of insufficient demand) grew 11.4% from July to September of this
year, mitigating what would have been a far worse slowdown resulting
from global difficulties.
Indeed while the gloomy external situation, including the EU debt
crisis and a sluggish U.S. economy, has moderated Malaysia’s trade
surplus somewhat this year, the country has still managed to produce a
surplus year after year. Like many nations afflicted by the 1997 Asian
Financial Crisis, Malaysia’s balance of trade, following the devaluation
that year, has remained positive since recovering in 1998.
Unemployment has moderated following a 2008-2009 jump, generally
improving and reaching 3.3% in September of this year. Third quarter
inflation came in at just 1.4%, and even the inflationary spike of last
year didn’t see rates hit 4% year-on-year (YonY).
Hong Kong papers recently
pondered why the Kuala Lumpa exchange this year has been the most
active Asian market besides Japan in terms of Initial Public Offerings
(IPOs). Hong Kong, Singapore and the Chinese mainland have lagged far
behind. Meanwhile Malaysia is planning to diversify its export sectors
to further protect the economy from the dangers of overreliance on
foreign demand for manufactured goods.
One structural challenge for Malaysia going forward is to increase
labor productivity. Malaysia led developing Asia in terms of GDP per
person in 1950, but was eclipsed by both Taiwan and South Korea in the
1970s. Taiwan last year had more than double the productivity of
Malaysia when measured this year, whilst South Korean workers’
productivity was higher by more than a third. Malaysia is aiming to
increase productivity (measured by Gross National Income per person
employed rather than GDP per person employed) from $9,500 to $15,000 by
2020. If Malaysia can achieve this goal, it would mean that the country
will have at long last emerged from the so called “middle-income trap”.
Whilst it looks like finally Malaysia may be on course to escape
“middle income” status, the predicament is called a trap for a reason.
Early gains in a developing nation, including exploiting cheap labor
and resources, allow productivity and incomes to grow to middle levels.
Most emerging markets get stuck at this level or even regress (as
Brazil has done recently) because to climb higher requires different,
more complex changes which must also be maintained for decades –
including the development of high quality soft infrastructure (including
education), a predictable business climate, and a young population.
These include strong regulatory bodies free of corruption and willing to
combat it elsewhere, universities with global reputations, advanced
hospitals and elites willing to allow such reform. Many countries
encounter social and political resistance if such reforms are attempted,
or suffer from stresses resulting (perversely) from their preceding
strong growth.
Malaysia is not alone in trying to escape this trap. China, Sri
Lanka and Thailand currently lead Indonesia and the Philippines in terms
of GDP per person employed. Brazil is ahead of all of them, but is
moving in the wrong direction, with productivity falling since the
investment heavy growth model slowed down in the 1970s. The question,
then, is whether Malaysia can buck this trend?
Economic Models
- The US model is free market or liberalization theory.
- The Euro zone model is an integration theory
- The Japan model for the best mixed system-ideological theory with government leader and guidance.
- The German model for the best incorporation of social factors into market economy.
- The New Zealand model for the best small country model since 2005.
- The Chile model for the best application of Austrian school of economics.
- The China model for the best of market system with dictator.
Which economic model should Malaysia adopt in order to be a developed nation?